Thursday, November 28, 2013

Understanding your credit score



Each bureau uses a modified version of the Fair Isaacs scoring method. Equifax has the BEACON system, Experian has the Experian/Fair Isaac Risk System, and TransUnion has the classic FICO Risk Score system.
It is important to know that each bureau uses a slightly different scoring method because scores will be different. They all weigh the report about the same as far as what is important and what is less important. Credit scores typically range from 300 to 850. Anything below 600 is considered high risk and a score of about 720 is great with the best rates available.

Understanding how much weight is put on late payments versus inquiries is helpful when trying to maximize your credit score.
- 35% of your score is based on your payment history. It makes sense that the most emphasis is placed on if your payments have been on time since lenders think if you are late with other payments you may be late with theirs.
- 30% is based on outstanding debt. If you have a couple car loans, a mortgage, and several maxed out credit cards a lender will worry that you are on the verge of bankruptcy. On the other hand if your balances are all less than 50% of the available credit, lenders will see you are responsible and will be more willing to extend you credit.
- 15% of the score is based on the length of time you’ve had credit. The longer a line of credit has been open the better it is for you. This is why it can hurt your credit if you cancel that credit card you have had for years.
- 10% of your score is based on new credit. Opening new credit accounts will hurt your overall score. Inquires are also included in this category. Hard inquires from lenders will hurt your score while soft inquires from you will not.
As you can see 65% of your score is based on making your payments and your percentage of available credit so it is very important to keep an eye on these.

When to use credit Repair Companies

      

          What if you have done all that and still cannot remove some of the negative marks on your credit? That is when it is time for a credit repair company.
I had an error on my credit report where a company had listed two accounts for me. I only had one account and the other account was hurting my credit. I disputed the false account and told them I only had one. They some how verified the account anyway. I tried calling the company to tell them it was false, but nobody would return my calls.That is when I went looking for a credit repair company to fight for me. Within 30 days they removed the false account and my score increased quite a bit.
When looking for a credit repair company, there are a few things to find out.
- Do they have attorneys on staff to deal with the bureaus? For some reason an attorney can get the bureaus to listen more than a regular private citizen.
- They must have a refund policy. This is important. If the company performs as they say they do, they will offer a money back guarantee. If they don’t do what they say they will do, you shouldn’t have to pay. A satisfaction guarantee where they will continue to work for you until you are satisfied doesn’t mean much if they can’t get the job done in the first place.
- Check for testimonials. The company should advertise their satisfied clients. If you can’t find any on their site there may not be any at all.
- The company should have years of experience. Startup companies may not have the relations and “know how” that come with experience. Be sure the company has been around.
Lexington Law is one credit repair company that meets the requirements above. They have been in business for over 15 years and have a proven track record with more than 500,000 clients.

Monday, November 25, 2013

A Watched Pot Never Boils: น้ำไม่เดือด คนเดือด

เวลาที่เราจดจ่ออยู่กับสิ่งใดสิ่งหนึ่งทั้งที่รู้ว่า สิ่งเหล่านั้นเกิดขึ้นตามกาลตามปัจจัย ไม่อาจจะเปลี่ยนแปลงได้
น้ำไม่เดือด คนเดือด
เช่น เมื่อไหร่จะถึงเช้าวันจันทร์เสียที อยากจะปรี่ไปทำงานจะแย่แล้ว (จะมีใครคิดแบบนี้จริงๆ ไหมคะ ^_^) เราก็จะค้นพบว่า วันจันทร์ที่เรารอคอยนั้น ดูเหมือนจะมาไม่ถึงเสียที ทั้งๆ ที่เวลาก็เดินไปตามปกติของมัน สำหรับฝรั่งที่ดื่มกาแฟกันทุกเช้า เค้าจะเคยชินกับการต้มน้ำ และรู้ว่าการรอให้น้ำเดือด โดยเฉพาะอย่างยิ่งในเวลาที่รีบๆ จะสายแหล่มิสายแหล่นี่มันทรมานใจขนาดไหน ดังนั้นเมื่อจะเตือนใจใครให้รู้จักการปล่อยใจให้รอคอยอย่างอดทน เพราะสิ่งนั้นเกิดขึ้นได้ตามกาลตามเวลาที่เหมาะสมเท่านั้น เราจะเอาการจดจ่อของเราไปแทรกแซงไม่ได้ เค้าก็จะพูดกันว่า A watched pot never boils
เวลาจดจ่อให้น้ำเดือด แล้วมันดันไม่เดือด แทนที่น้ำจะปุดๆ กลับกลายเป็นใจเราเสียมากกว่าที่ตุบๆ ไม่หยุดด้วยความโมโห จึงเกิดสำนวน Boil over ที่แปลเหมือน เดือดดาล หรือ โมโห ในบ้านเรานี่เอง ซึ่งนอกจากจะใช้เดี่ยวๆ เพื่อบอกความรู้สึกว่า I’m really boiled over. ฉันกำลังเดือดสุดๆ อยู่ตอนนี้ เรายังมักจะเห็นในรูป Boil over with anger หรือ rage ซึ่งย้ำเข้าไปว่า เดือดดาลด้วยแรงโทสะ ซึ่งก็คือ Anger หรือ Rage ซึ่งมีความหมายว่า ความโกรธ แต่ถ้าอยากจะบอกว่า เดือดจนจะแผดเผาใครได้ ต้องใช้ Boil over for someone เช่น I’m really boiled over for him. ฉันละเดือดเค้าจริงๆ เป็นต้นค่ะ
เคยมีนักปรัชญาเอาทฤษฎีทางฟิสิกส์ที่ชื่อ Chaos Theory หรือทฤษฎีแห่งความยุ่งเหยิง มาอธิบายปรากฏการณ์ที่ตรงกับสำนวน A watched pot never boils เอาไว้ว่าสิ่งที่พอจะคาดเดาหรือทำนายผลได้ จะกลายเป็นความยุ่งเหยิงที่คาดเดาผลลัพธ์ไม่ได้เลยหากถูกแทรกแซงแม้ด้วยปัจจัยที่ดูแสนจะเล็กน้อย ซึ่งปัจจัยที่แทรกแซงน้ำไม่ให้เดือดเสียทีนี้ก็คือ “ใจ” เรานี่เอง หากเอา “ใจ” วางไว้ในที่ที่มันควรจะอยู่ สิ่งต่างๆ ก็จะดำเนินไปตามวิถีไม่มีใครต้องร้อนรน



ที่มา:thairath

8 ตัวอย่างภาษาอังกฤษแบบผิดๆ ที่เป็นคำฮิตติดปากคนไทย



8 ตัวอย่างภาษาอังกฤษแบบผิดๆ ที่เป็นคำฮิตติดปากคนไทย

          ในปัจจุบันมีคำทับศัพท์ภาษาอังกฤษที่คนไทยใช้กันจนติดปากอยู่มากมาย แต่คุณเคยรู้ไหมว่ามีบางคำที่ฝรั่งเค้าไม่ได้ใช้อย่างที่เราพูดกันติดปาก วันนี้จึงเสนอคำศัพท์สัก 8 ตัวอย่างที่คนไทยมักใช้อย่างผิดๆ จนติดเป็นนิสัยพร้อมทั้งคำที่ถูกต้องซึ่งคุณควรนำไปใช้เวลาคุยกับฝรั่ง พร้อมแล้วมาเริ่มกันเลย

1.อินเทรนด์ (in trend) คำนี้อินเทรนด์มากๆ เอ๊ย…ฮิตมากๆ ในปัจจุบัน สามารถได้ยินตามรายการวิทยุหรือโทรทัศน์ทั่วไป เพราะใช้กันทั่วบ้านทั่วเมือง เช่น เด็กสมัยนี้ถ้าจะให้อินเทรนด์ต้องตามแฟชั่นเกาหลี ซึ่งบางทีเวลาคุณต้องการพูดว่า “มันทันสมัย” คุณอาจจะติดปากว่า “It is in trend.” คำว่า “ทันสมัย” ฝรั่งเค้าไม่ใช้คำว่า “in trend” อย่างคนไทยเค้าจะใช้คำว่า “trendy” หรือ “fashionable” ซึ่งเป็นคำคุณศัพท์ที่คุณสามารถวางไว้หน้าคำนามที่ต้องการขยาย เช่น a trendy haircut ทรงผมที่ทันสมัย, a fashionable restaurant ร้านอาหารที่ทันสมัย หรือจะไว้หลัง verb to be เช่น It is trendy. หรือ It is fashionable. ก็ได้

2.เว่อร์(over) เช่น เธอคนนั้นทำอะไรเว่อร์ๆ She is over. ไม่มีความหมายแต่อย่างใดในภาษาอังกฤษ ฝรั่งที่ได้ยินคุณพูดเช่นนี้ คงมึนตึบ พร้อมทำสีหน้างงว่ามันหมายถึงอะไรเหรอ? พูดถึงคำนี้ คนไทยน่าจะหมายถึงการพูดเกินจริงหรือทำเกินจริง ซึ่งถ้าพูดเกินจริง ควรจะใช้คำศัพท์ที่ว่า “exaggerate” เป็นคำกิริยา อ่านว่า เอก-แซ้ก-เจ่อ-เรท ตัวอย่างเช่น
“He said you walked 30 miles.” เค้าบอกว่าคุณเดินตั้ง 30 ไมล์
“No – he’s exaggerating. It was only about 15.” ไม่หรอก เค้าพูดเว่อร์ (เกินจริง) มันก็แค่ 15 ไมล์เอง
ดังนั้น ถ้าจะบอกว่า เธอพูดเว่อร์น่ะ ก็บอกว่า You’re exaggerating. หรือจะบอกเค้าว่า อย่าพูดเว่อร์ๆ น่ะ อาจใช้ว่า Don’t exaggerate. ส่วนอาการเว่อร์อีกแบบคือการทำเกินจริง เราจะใช้คำกิริยาที่ว่า “overact” เช่น You’re overacting. เธอทำเว่อร์เกิน (แสดงอารมณ์เกินจริง)

3.ดูหนัง soundtrack เวลาคุณจะบอกใครว่า ฉันต้องการดูหนังฝรั่งที่พากย์ภาษาอังกฤษ อย่าพูดว่า “I want to watch a soundtrack film.” แต่ควรจะใช้ว่า “I want to watch an English film.” เพราะความหมายของคำว่า “soundtrack” คือ ดนตรีที่อยู่ในภาพยนตร์ ต่างหาก
ถ้าเราจะพูดถึงหนังฝรั่งที่พากย์เสียงภาษาไทย เราต้องบอกว่า “I want to watch an English film that is dubbed into Thai.” เพราะคำกิริยาว่า “dub” คือพากย์เสียงจากต้นแบบในหนังหรือรายการโทรทัศน์ไปเป็นภาษาอื่น ส่วนหนังที่มีคำบรรยายใต้ภาพเราเรียกว่า “a subtitled film” ซึ่งคำบรรยายที่อยู่ใต้ภาพ เราเรียกว่า “subtitles” (ต้องมี s ต่อท้ายเสมอนะครับ) เช่น a French film with English subtitles หนังฝรั่งเศสที่มีคำบรรยายใต้ภาพเป็นภาษาอังกฤษ
หนังบางเรื่องจะมีคำบรรยายใต้ภาพเป็นภาษาเดียวกับที่นักแสดงพูด เรามีศัพท์เรียกเฉพาะว่า “closed-captioned films/คำหวงห้าม/television programs” หรือ อาจเขียนย่อๆ ว่า “CC” เช่น You should watch a closed-captioned film to improve your English. คุณควรจะดูหนังฝรั่งที่มีคำบรรยายภาษาอังกฤษเพื่อพัฒนาภาษาอังกฤษของคุณ

4.นักศึกษาปี 1 คนไทยมักเรียกว่า “freshy” ซึ่งฝรั่งไม่รู้เรื่องเพราะไม่มีการบัญญัติศัพท์คำนี้ในภาษาอังกฤษ เค้าจะใช้คำว่า “fresher” หรือ “freshman” เช่น He is a fresher. หรือ He is a freshman. หรือ He is a first-year student. เขาเป็นนักศึกษาปี 1 ส่วนปีอื่นๆ คนไทยเรียกถูกแล้วครับ คือ ปี 2 เราเรียก a sophomore, ปี 3 เรียกว่า a junior และ ปี 4 เรียกว่า a senior

5.อัดหรือบันทึก คนไทยมักพูดทับศัพท์ว่า เร็คคอร์ด (record) คำๆ นี้สามารถเป็นได้ทั้งคำนามและคำกิริยา เพียงแค่เปลี่ยนตำแหน่ง stress กล่าวคือ ถ้าจะใช้เป็นคำนามที่แปลว่า แผ่นเสียงหรือสถิติ ให้ขึ้นเสียงสูงที่พยางค์แรก คือ “เร็ค-คอร์ด” เช่น He wants to buy a record. เขาต้องการซื้อแผ่นเสียง, I broke my own record. ฉันทำลายสถิติของฉันเอง แต่ถ้าคุณจะหมายถึงคำกิริยาที่แปลว่า อัดหรือบันทึก ต้อง stress พยางค์หลัง ซึ่งจะอ่านว่า “รี-คอร์ด” เช่น I’ll record the film and we can all watch it later. ฉันจะอัดหนัง เราจะได้เก็บไว้ดูทีหลังได้ ส่วนเครื่องบันทึก เราเรียกว่า “recorder” อ่านว่า รี-คอร์-เดอร์

6.ต่างคนต่างจ่าย เรามักใช้ American share รับรองว่าฝรั่ง(ต่อให้เป็นชาวอเมริกันด้วยครับ) ได้ยินแล้ว งงแน่นอน ถ้าคุณจะหมายถึงต่างคนต่างจ่ายให้ใช้ว่า “Let’s go Dutch.” หรือ “Go Dutch (with somebody).” อันนี้ไม่แน่ใจเหมือนกันว่าเป็นธรรมเนียมของชาวดัตช์หรือเปล่า? ที่ต่างคนต่างจ่ายเลยมีสำนวนอย่างนี้ หรือคุณอาจจะบอกตรงๆ เลยว่า “You pay for yourself.” คือเป็นอันรู้กันว่าต่างคนต่างจ่าย แต่ถ้าคุณต้องการเป็นเจ้ามือ(ไม่ใช่เล่นไพ่นะคะ)เลี้ยงมื้อนี้เอง คุณควรพูดว่า “It’s my treat this time.” หรือ “My treat.” หรือ “It’s on me.” หรือ “All is on me.” หรือ “I’ll pay for you this time.” ทั้งหมดแปลว่า มื้อนี้ฉันจ่ายเอง ส่วนถ้าจะบอกเพื่อนว่า คราวหน้าแกค่อยเลี้ยงฉันคืน ให้บอกว่า “It’s your treat next time.”

7.ขอฉันแจม (jam) ด้วยคน ในกรณีนี้คำว่า “แจม” น่าจะหมายถึง “ร่วมด้วย” เช่น We are going to eat outside. Do you want to jam? เรากำลังจะออกไปกินข้าวข้างนอก เธอจะไปด้วยมั้ย? ในภาษาอังกฤษไม่ใช้คำว่า jam ในกรณีแบบนี้ ซึ่งควรจะใช้ว่า “Do you want to join us?”, “Do you want to come with us?” หรือ “Do you want to come along?” จะดีกว่า

8.เขามีแบ็ค (back) ดี “He has a good back.” ฝรั่งคงงงว่ามันเกี่ยวอะไรกับข้างหลังของเค้า เพราะ back แปลว่า หลัง (อวัยวะ) แต่คุณกำลังจะพูดถึงมีคนคอยสนับสนุน ซึ่งต้องใช้ “a backup” ซึ่งหมายถึง คนหรือสิ่งของที่ช่วยสนับสนุน ช่วยเหลือ เกื้อกูล เป็นกำลังใจให้
นี่เป็นเพียงแค่ 8 คำเบื้องต้นที่นำมาฝากเพื่อนๆ ซึ่งในชีวิตประจำวันยังมีคำอีกมากมายที่ยังถูกใช้แบบผิดๆ โอกาสหน้า แอดมิน จะนำมาฝากกันใหม่


ที่มา : ครูบ้านนอก

Externalities


    A second important source of market failure is externalities or ‘spillover effects’.
These arise when an economic activity affects a third party directly rather than
through the market. The competition model assumes that both producers and
consumers bear the entire cost and enjoy the entire benefit created by their economic actions. This assumption is frequently breached in practice. The resulting
spillover effects reflect an inefficiency of the free-market system.

    Externalities can be either positive or negative. Positive externalities, also called
external benefits, bestow a benefit on a third party.Correspondingly, a negative externality,also referred to as an external cost, imposes a cost on a third party, involving a loss of utility.A further distinction can be made between producers and
consumers. Externalities can result either from the consumption activities of
some individuals or from the production process of firms.

    The different types of externalities are summarised in Figure 8.1. Examples are
given for each of the four categories. All four types of externalities lead to inefficiencies when the market system is left to operate freely. The free market
provides too little of the activities providing positive externalities and too much
of those with negative externalities. In that sense, ‘positive’ externalities are just
as ‘inefficient’ as ‘negative’ externalities.

    To illustrate the efficiency loss from spillover effects, we begin with the
example of a negative production externality. Imagine a chemical plant which channels its polluted effluents into the nearest river. Imagine also that, downstream,
there is a factory which needs clean water, and, therefore, must incur costs
in cleaning the water. Finally, assume that the resulting loss in profits for the
downstream factory can be measured in money terms and is a constant fraction
of the factory’s output. This situation is represented in Figure 8.2.

    Assume for simplicity that the chemical factory can sell at a given price OP, i.e.
it faces a horizontal demand curve and thus price # marginal revenue. Its
marginal costs increase with output. The production costs borne by the firm are
denoted by PMC, which stands for private marginal cost. Profit maximisation
drives the firm to produce up to OP # PMC, hence the amount OQ_1 of chemicals
is produced. However, the factory’s operating costs do not encompass the totality
of costs created by the manufacture of its output. Costs borne by the downstream
factory in cleaning the water need to be accounted for. Suppose these amount to
EF per unit of chemical output. In order to represent total production costs perunit, we add EF to PMC to obtain SMC, the social marginal cost. In the case of a
negative production externality, the social cost is greater than the private cost of
production. From society’s point of view, the costs to the downstream factory
should be added to the outlays of the chemical company. Hence, the optimality
condition is that OP # SMC. It would be socially optimal to produce OQ_2 rather
than OQ_1._11

    This example shows that, in the presence of negative externalities, the free
market leads to an over-provision of the goods concerned. In the opposite scenario
– where the production or consumption of a certain good creates external
benefits – a free market results in too low a level of production or consumption.
   
    Note that economics tends to resist any absolutist approach to the pollution
problem. The existence of external costs such as pollution does not generally
provide an economic justification for the total suppression of the underlying
activity. In our example, the closure of the chemicals plant is not required for

efficiency, merely a reduction in output to the level OQ_2. There is a trade-off between the utility lost by the sufferers of pollution and the utility gained by the producers and consumers of the good whose production gave rise to the externality. In this sense some pollution is, for this reason, usually better than no pollution. Only if the negative spillover EF were so large as to push up SMC beyond the demand curve over the whole range of output would it be most efficient to shut down the factory completely. This is not just a theoretical possibility – several polluting plants of Central Europe were closed down during the 1990s for this reason.

Monday, November 4, 2013

Information failures


    

    The fourth type of market failure arises because real-world consumers and producers are not perfectly informed about all goods and prices. Where lack of such
knowledge is significant, information failure leads to an inefficient outcome in a
market system. A good example is the health effect of tobacco consumption. In a
free market, no firm has an incentive to circulate information about the hazards
of smoking. The demand curve for cigarettes has shifted outwards above what the
level would be if information was symmetric. It is obvious that tobacco companies
have no incentive to rectify the asymmetry. Nor will any individual have an
incentive to provide such enlightenment. Hence the need for government to step
in. Information failures also provide a rationale for public sector involvement
in activities as diverse as drugs testing, health inspection of restaurants, banking
regulation, insurance and the provision of job search centres for the unemployed.

    These four sources of market failure point to the need for government
intervention. The form of such intervention is the subject of the next section.



Government intervention

    The public sector constitutes the major alternative to free private markets. Hence,
a call for government intervention is generally regarded as the logical consequence
of the diagnosed market failures. As we have seen, public sector activity accounts for sizeable proportions of all countries’ national output. Even in a country as market-oriented as the US, government expenditure accounts for a third of GDP.

    Governments can influence economic activity in three major ways: taxation
and subsidisation, regulation and public provision. Together, they constitute the
main elements in the government’s microeconomic policy.

    In evaluating the different modes of intervention, attention is focused on their
efficiency effects rather than the income distribution effects. Of course, in many
instances the modality of intervention may be determined by equity or, indeed,
purely political considerations. For example, it may be ‘easier’ in political terms
to boost farm incomes by raising food prices than by providing highly transparent
subsidies of an equivalent amount. For that reason, arguments about the
inefficiency of one mode of transfer over another may often fall on deaf ears. Yet
research on more effective ways of intervening, and on the costs and benefits of
different forms of intervention, clearly helps rational decision making.


Taxes and subsidies

    Taxes and subsidies are used extensively to distribute income.
 Subsidies require taxes to finance them, and this raises questions concerning the
optimal structure of taxes. We have already referred to the rules which should
govern indirect taxes: impose high tax rates on activities with low price elasticity
of demand and low broadly-based rates on all other activities, assuming
that the motivation for imposing taxes is simply to obtain revenue for the
government.
   
    While most taxes are imposed for this reason, there is another motivation
which merits discussion. Taxes can sometimes be imposed not primarily in order
to collect revenue, but to direct resources in a particular direction – e.g. a pollution
tax. In other instances, the two motives overlap.By the same token,
while the bulk of subsidies are transfer payments to lower-income groups, many
are provided in order to encourage particular activities and regions

    Returning to the example of the polluting chemicals factory, it is easily shown that, if the government taxes the plant by the amount EF for every unit produced, the firm’s private marginal cost is increased and equals the social marginal cost, leading the firm to produce the socially optimum output level of OQ_2. By taxing the polluter by the value of the damage caused, the government is said to have ‘internalised’ the externality. In general, an optimal government policy taxes firms or individuals for the value of the external cost they cause and subsidises them to the value of the external benefit they create. This is the rationale underlying, for instance, taxes on fuel, and subsidies for education and industrial training.

Public goods


    The third main category of market failure arises because of the existence of public
goods. A public good is defined as being non-excludable and non-rivalrous in consumption.A private good, by contrast, is both excludable and rivalrous in consumption.

    For the explanation of these concepts, consider the example of an army, representing a pure public good, and an apple, a private good. A good is excludable if individuals can be prevented from enjoying its benefits. It is easy to withhold an
apple from someone, hence it is excludable. However, if an army successfully
defends a country against an invading force, then all inhabitants of the protected
country necessarily benefit and no one can be excluded. National defence is thus non-excludable.

    Non-rivalry means that the consumption of a good by an additional person
does not preclude someone else also consuming it. Put more technically, a nonrivalrous good is subject to a zero marginal cost of consumption. If one individual
eats the apple, this precludes anyone else from eating it. Apples are thus
rivalrous goods. If the army protects the nation, however, all citizens are free to
enjoy the feeling of security that protection engenders. The fact that I feel secure
does not in any way preclude your feeling secure, nor does it add to the security
bill. Consequently, national defence is also a non-rivalrous good.

    Public and private goods do not constitute sharply delineated categories. There
is a continuous range of products between the two opposite poles, pure public
goods and pure private goods. Figure 8.3 tentatively places some examples of different goods within this continuous range, differentiating between the intensity
of rivalry and the degree of excludability of these goods. The fact that most goods
are roughly situated around the diagonal starting at the origin illustrates that
there is a strong link between rivalry and excludability.

    In the bottom left corner of the diagram are listed some pure public goods. If a
country’s air is clean, if its territory is safe from foreign armies and if its currency is
stable, then the benefits of these achievements can be withheld from no citizen of
this country, nor does it cost more to provide them if the resident population grows.
They are, therefore, unambiguously non-excludable and non-rivalrous. At the other
extreme are pure private goods, situated in the top right corner of Figure 8.3. Apples,
cars and books are clearly excludable and rivalrous. The most interesting cases,
however, are located between these two poles. Museums and art galleries are to some extent non-rivalrous. My enjoyment from viewing a Caravaggio today in no sense diminishes the possibility of your enjoying it tomorrow – hence it is non-rivalrous.But if everybody crowds into the gallery at the same time, each person’s enjoyment will diminish and, in that sense, the art gallery becomes a rivalrous good. It is also excludable – one can change the admission fee to the gallery.



    Another example of a good which is only partly ‘public’ by nature is a motorway.
Again, up to a certain point of congestion, additional users cause only minor, if any, diminution of existing users’ utility. It is also possible to exclude certain drivers from the use of these roads by setting up checkpoints or toll booths. Obviously, it is more costly to control the access to a motorway than to monitor the entrance of a museum or art gallery. A motorway is thus less ‘excludable’ than a museum. This is important, because very few things are technically non-excludable. As technology changes, some things become less excludable and some more excludable .The real issue is the cost of exclusion, which is an example of transaction costs. Also, improved technology and income growth have made some hitherto non-rivalrous goods become rivalrous.


    Markets fail in the presence of pure public goods because of the so-called ‘freerider’ problem. It may be very costly to provide a public good,but everyone can benefit from it no matter whether he or she has contributed to its financing. Self-interested individuals have an incentive to avoid paying for the good in the hope that others will provide it. In other words, utility-maximising individuals try to free-ride on the others. If all individuals reason in that fashion,none of the public good is produced, even if the aggregate cost of providing the good is much lower than the sum of potential utility gains. The market, a system based on non-cooperative interaction of selfish individuals, leads to zero provision of pure public goods. If the aggregate benefit potentially derived from the public good exceeds its total cost of provision, this could be a very inefficient outcome. The non-rivalrous character of a public good means that the market should produce more than it does, while its non-excludable character means that the market will never have the incentive to do so.

Sunday, November 3, 2013

Externalities


    A second important source of market failure is externalities or ‘spillover effects’.
These arise when an economic activity affects a third party directly rather than
through the market. The competition model assumes that both producers and
consumers bear the entire cost and enjoy the entire benefit created by their economic actions. This assumption is frequently breached in practice. The resulting
spillover effects reflect an inefficiency of the free-market system.

    Externalities can be either positive or negative. Positive externalities, also called
external benefits, bestow a benefit on a third party.Correspondingly, a negative externality,also referred to as an external cost, imposes a cost on a third party, involving a loss of utility.A further distinction can be made between producers and
consumers. Externalities can result either from the consumption activities of
some individuals or from the production process of firms.

    The different types of externalities are summarised in Figure 8.1. Examples are
given for each of the four categories. All four types of externalities lead to inefficiencies when the market system is left to operate freely. The free market
provides too little of the activities providing positive externalities and too much
of those with negative externalities. In that sense, ‘positive’ externalities are just
as ‘inefficient’ as ‘negative’ externalities.

    To illustrate the efficiency loss from spillover effects, we begin with the
example of a negative production externality. Imagine a chemical plant which channels its polluted effluents into the nearest river. Imagine also that, downstream,
there is a factory which needs clean water, and, therefore, must incur costs
in cleaning the water. Finally, assume that the resulting loss in profits for the
downstream factory can be measured in money terms and is a constant fraction
of the factory’s output. This situation is represented in Figure 8.2.


    Assume for simplicity that the chemical factory can sell at a given price OP, i.e.
it faces a horizontal demand curve and thus price # marginal revenue. Its
marginal costs increase with output. The production costs borne by the firm are
denoted by PMC, which stands for private marginal cost. Profit maximisation
drives the firm to produce up to OP # PMC, hence the amount OQ_1 of chemicals
is produced. However, the factory’s operating costs do not encompass the totality
of costs created by the manufacture of its output. Costs borne by the downstream
factory in cleaning the water need to be accounted for. Suppose these amount to
EF per unit of chemical output. In order to represent total production costs perunit, we add EF to PMC to obtain SMC, the social marginal cost. In the case of a
negative production externality, the social cost is greater than the private cost of
production. From society’s point of view, the costs to the downstream factory
should be added to the outlays of the chemical company. Hence, the optimality
condition is that OP # SMC. It would be socially optimal to produce OQ_2 rather
than OQ_1._11

    This example shows that, in the presence of negative externalities, the free
market leads to an over-provision of the goods concerned. In the opposite scenario
– where the production or consumption of a certain good creates external
benefits – a free market results in too low a level of production or consumption.
   
    Note that economics tends to resist any absolutist approach to the pollution
problem. The existence of external costs such as pollution does not generally
provide an economic justification for the total suppression of the underlying
activity. In our example, the closure of the chemicals plant is not required for

efficiency, merely a reduction in output to the level OQ_2. There is a trade-off between the utility lost by the sufferers of pollution and the utility gained by the producers and consumers of the good whose production gave rise to the externality. In this sense some pollution is, for this reason, usually better than no pollution. Only if the negative spillover EF were so large as to push up SMC beyond the demand curve over the whole range of output would it be most efficient to shut down the factory completely. This is not just a theoretical possibility – several polluting plants of Central Europe were closed down during the 1990s for this reason.

Market failures


Economic theory has shown that a perfectly competitive economy, guided by
Adam Smith’s ‘invisible hand’, attains a Pareto-efficient allocation of resources.
But most real-world markets violate at least some of the assumptions which
underlie the economists’ idealised free-market model. Such deviations of real
markets from the efficient model economy are called ‘market failures’. Market
failure can arise for four main reasons: 1. monopoly power, 2. externalities,
3. public goods, and 4. information asymmetries.


Monopoly power

    The distortionary effects of monopoly have already been analysed.
Monopoly involves a breach of the rule that marginal cost # price by introducing
a wedge between marginal cost of production of a good and the utility it provides
the marginal consumer as measured by prices. Monopoly pricing also creates an
income distribution effect. Monopoly profits are earned at the expense of the
consumers, who pay a higher price relative to what they would pay in a competitive
market. This is the reason why consumer organisations oppose monopolies
and cartels, and lobby their governments for stricter competition legislation.

    However, the gain of monopoly producers at the expense of consumers can
involve serious losses at both domestic and international level. The World Bank
has estimated that cumulative overcharges to developing countries over the life
of the cartels in vitamins, citric acid, lysine ,steel tubes and graphic electrodes ranged from $3bn to $7bn._8 Uncompetitive behaviour also reduces economic efficiency. As we move from a competitive situation, with a large quantity supplied at a low price, to a monopoly, where a smaller quantity is supplied at a higher price, what occurs is not a zero-sum redistribution of income from consumers to producers, but a net loss of utility to society at large. This is the ‘deadweight loss’ of monopoly.

    The deadweight loss, as described above, is a static phenomenon relating to the
market situation at one point in time. Empirical estimates of the deadweight
losses caused by existing monopolies or oligopolies typically amount to only
a few percentage points of the values of total sales in the particular industry.
A forerunner in trying to measure the deadweight loss, Arnold Harberger was surprised to find that such welfare losses amounted to a mere 0.1 per cent of US
national income in the 1920s._9 Later, detailed studies have come up with much
higher estimates, though these have been subject to a wide range of variation.

    As readers will recall from Chapter 7, the efficiency losses from monopoly
occur over time. Monopolists or oligopolists have less of an incentive than competitive firms to maintain efficiency, to innovate and to improve their services.
Indeed, as Hicks once noted in a famous dictum, ‘the greatest of monopoly profits
is a quiet life’._10 This is a central theme of the Austrian School. The pressure of
competition forces firms to aim at lowering their costs continuously,
while sheltered firms do not have to be so concerned about their costs and the
improvement of output quality. The losses due to such so-called X-inefficiencies
are even more difficult to estimate empirically than deadweight losses.
Nevertheless, in many circumstances they outweigh the deadweight losses
stressed by economic theory. The Cecchini Report, for example, estimated that
the X-efficiency losses of nontariff barriers on intra-European trade amounted to

2 per cent of GNP in the late 1980s.

The equity efficiency trade-off


    Economics is the study of trade-offs between different uses of scarce resources. Firms continuously trade off current benefits from the distribution of dividends against future benefits from retaining these profits and reinvesting them in the business. Managers and workers trade off the career fruits of long and hard working hours against the joys of leisure time. Consumers trade off the utility that could have been attained by buying good X or Y for the utility derived from purchasing good Z instead.

    Arguably, the most important, and certainly the most hotly debated, economic
trade-off is the political choice between equity and efficiency. Conventional wisdom
suggests that more equity leads to less efficiency, because equalisation of income and wealth among individuals can reduce work incentives, as well as the aggregate level of savings and investment .Conversely, unrestrained market forces result in inequitable outcomes or, in the famous words of Arthur
Okun, ‘dollars transgress on rights’.

    Economists have attempted to check the link between equity and efficiency empirically.This entails finding satisfactory measures of the two concepts. Efficiency is usually measured by reference to average GNP per capita.
    Measuring equity is trickier. Economists associate equity with an even distribution of income and wealth among individuals. The main measure of income distribution is
derived from the Lorenz curve, presented in Diagram 1.

    The Lorenz curve plots the cumulative share of income and wealth in ascending order against the cumulative percentage of population. In Diagram 1, for instance, 80 percent of the population receives only 50 per cent of the total income, while the richest 20 per cent enjoy the remaining 50 per cent of the pie. The poorest fifth of the population receives a mere 3 per cent of national income and wealth. This Lorenz curve thus depicts a society with considerable inequality. A country with perfect equality of income and wealth, where each individual controls the same amount of material goods,exhibits a straight Lorenz curve, called the ‘line of equality’.

    The more strongly the Lorenz curve diverges from the line of equality, the greater
the degree of inequality. This can be captured by a simple measure. The Gini coefficient is the proportion of the area delimited by the line of equality and the Lorenz curve, relative to the total area between the line of equality and the horizontal axis. The index can take values between 0 and 1, where 0 means perfect equality and 1 represents complete inequality.

    Diagram 2 shows Gini indices for a selection of high-income countries. The upper
bars represent the distribution of disposable income among individuals. The lower
shaded bars show what level of income inequality would have prevailed in
the absence of government redistribution through progressive taxes and welfare
benefits.



    Two important conclusions can be drawn from Diagram 2.

1. Market forces alone produce highly unequal income distributions. The ‘before redistribution’Gini indices for the 10 sample countries are contained in the range
0.33_–_0.44.
2. Post-tax distributions are much less unequal than pre-tax distributions. The ‘after
redistribution’ coefficients lie in the range 0.20_–_0.34. Tax and welfare payments
reduce inequality to a significant extent. 

    Wealthy countries tend to be more equal in overall income distribution than poor
countries._2 The UK, however, has experienced deteriorating inequality in recent years.Up to the 1980s its Gini coefficient was 10 points below the US level; by the 1990s the gap had fallen to only 5 points._3 Equity and efficiency do not necessarily conflict. The 10 countries in Diagram 2 are all among the world’s very richest and some are quite egalitarian. In developing countries, higher inequality in income or land ownership tends to be associated with lower growth. It is argued that big income and land ownership differentials reflect underinvestment in education, divert government efforts from investment and growth promotion towards the abatement of social conflict, and reduce the majority’s incentive to save and invest.


    The relationship between equity and efficiency depends to some extent on individual attitudes and culture. In some societies, income inequalities are condemned less, and financial work incentives valued more, than in others. A political philosopher stated that ‘the combinations of equity and, say, economic growth attainable in a competitive market economy full of individualistic materialists might be rather different from those attainable in a co-operative economy run by and for ascetic altruists’._5 A poll conducted in 1990 showed that only 29 per cent of Americans thought it was the government’s job to reduce income differentials, while 60_–_70 per cent of Germans and Britons, and over 80 per cent of Italians and Austrians, were of that opinion._6 The debate continues.

Saturday, November 2, 2013

Government intervention and the market system


Government plays a major role in the economy. Among industrial countries, the
share of government spending in GDP ranges from 32 per cent in the US to 53 per
cent in Sweden._1 In addition to this, the authorities affect the business environment
through a myriad of taxes, rules and regulations. The purpose of this chapter is to analyse the contribution of government to economic welfare and
the business environment.

The objectives of government and business are to some extent in opposition.
The social objectives of government policy can impose restraints on a firm’s
behaviour in relation to employees and investment. Competition policy limits
the scope of business to acquire and exploit monopoly power, environmental
legislation can impose heavy financial burdens on industry, and progressive
income taxes impact severely on executive salaries. However, governments and
business also share much common ground. Both have an interest in fostering
growth, securing high levels of employment and promoting social harmony.
Hence, business should not allow itself to be cast in the role of opposing all
public intervention. Much of this intervention is desirable, necessary and
directly beneficial to business. This much has always been recognised in
economics. Adam Smith himself devoted a long chapter to discussing the
various functions of government. In addition to the provision of defence and
justice, he asserted that ‘the sovereign or commonwealth’ had a duty to erect
and maintain

    those public institutions and those public works which, though they may be in the
highest degree advantageous to a great society, are however of such a nature that the profit could never repay the expense to any individual or small number of individuals.

    The debate has come a long way since then, as we shall see.

    For four decades after the Second World War, the influence of government in
the economy grew at an unprecedented rate. Some of this growth was fuelled by
Keynesian ideas of macroeconomic management. We defer discussion of this
aspect of government intervention until Part II. This chapter focuses on the
microeconomic considerations that prompted governments to play a more active
role in the economy.

    The economics of government intervention have undergone extensive review
in recent decades and the tide of government expansion has turned. Whereas
50 years ago governments regarded nationalisation as a solution to market imperfections,nowadays the debate is about privatisation. Many no longer see the
welfare state as the solution to the problem of poverty, but rather as a possible
source of its exacerbation. Instead of providing people with pensions, governments
are encouraging people to make provision for the future for themselves.
Changing ideas have spilled over into changing budgets. Government spending
as a percentage of GDP has stopped increasing and in some countries has declined



Income distribution and the equity–efficiency trade-off
    Economics seeks to improve society’s material welfare. This seems a reasonable
definition of the aim of economic activity, although at various times in the past
other objectives have taken precedence. To some, economic activity was useful
primarily as a means of securing and maintaining political power. Colbert, the
influential finance minister of Louis XIV, saw as the main purpose of his subjects’
labour not the increase in their own happiness, but the enhancement of the glory
and power of their sovereign, who personified the nation. Despots, through the
centuries, have viewed economic activity primarily as a means of securing and
extending their power rather than of improving the welfare of the masses. Even
those who agree with the objective of maximising individual utilities may disagree
over the interpretation of what truly gives utility to us as human beings and
who is best equipped to judge.

    The value judgements underlying modern economics are derived from a philosophy of individualism and liberalism. Individualism means that what ultimately
counts is the utility every individual attains and that the utility of each individual should be given an equal weight. Liberalism signifies that individuals
should be free to decide what provides the greatest utility. Individual preferences
are taken as given. The task of the economist, in this view, is to advocate structures
which ensure that they are satisfied to the maximum extent, not to pass
judgement on them.

    It is important to distinguish between utility and income. The standard
assumption underlying economic reasoning is that the marginal utility of income
is positive, but decreases as income rises._2 ‘Economic man’ always prefers a higher income to a lower one, but the intensity of this preference diminishes as income rises. Ascetics, who are happiest with a minimal income, and Scrooges, for whom income becomes more important the more they have of it, are both excluded by this definition. A systematic relationship thus links utility to income. On the face
of it, the individualist principle of treating the utility of every person equally,
coupled with the assumption of declining marginal utility for all individuals,
would seem to imply that the total utility in society is maximised when income
is distributed perfectly evenly. However, few would advocate total income equalisation.

    There are two reasons for this. First, different people derive different amounts
of satisfaction from the same income levels. Material wealth does not matter
equally to all. Second, policies to achieve greater equality have an adverse effect
on incentives to work and enterprise and may, after a point, lead to a fall in total
income. The size of the cake to be distributed may be affected by how the cake is
sliced. In this metaphor, the slicing pattern represents the egalitarian or equity
factor and the size of the cake stands for the second major criterion of economic
judgement: efficiency._3 If the unweighted utility sum in a society can only be
maximised by allowing a degree of inequality, then the inequality outcome

might be preferred to perfect income equalisation.