Incentive regulation refers to the design
of incentives to ensure that producers keep prices and costs as low as
possible. The underlying assumption is that costs are not given but are
influenced by the incentives set by the regulatory authorities. If
there was no regulation
the privatised monopoly might well slip into the same
bad habits as the state
company it replaced. Whether the new regulation achieves
a superior outcome to
direct provision of the good or service by the state company depends on the
effectiveness of the regulatory system.
In the UK , following the privatisation of
telecoms, gas, water, electricity and railways, regulatory bodies were set up
for each industry.Their task was to prevent the abuse of monopoly power and to
find ways of promoting competition. This sounds easy, but regulators frequently
get into hot water in trying to achieve this objective.
There are several ways of regulating a privatised
industry with strong monopoly
elements:
1. Price #
marginal cost. One simple way would be to oblige the monopoly firm to
charge a price equal to
marginal cost, and provide a subsidy for any ensuing
loss. The drawback is the
cost of the subsidy and the difficulty of determining
marginal cost.
2. Breakeven
or average return on capital. Alternatively the regulator could insist on
a price that allows the
firm to just break even. This eliminates ‘monopoly’
profits but leaves wide
open the opportunity to reap the rewards of monopoly
in other guises .Some
regulators use a formula related to rate of return on capital which the
monopoly would not be permitted to exceed. This avoids the problem of direct
price control, but has the disadvantage of reducing the incentive to firms to
minimise costs, once the permitted profit rate has been attained. Rate of
return controls have been applied extensively in the US . Not surprisingly there have
been frequent disputes over the definition and measurement of rates of return
in these cases.
3. RPI minus
X. Another possibility is to set maximum prices. The UK authorities
have taken this approach.
Various types of price-capping formulas have been
used, known as ‘RPI minus
X’, whereby the regulator permits the firm’s price to
rise by no more than x
percentage points below the retail price
index .In a multi-product
monopoly, such as telecoms, the regulator may
opt for a tariff-basket
method, whereby the authorities decide which products
are placed in the basket
and how the various prices are to be weighted. This
usually means permitting
lower prices for price-elastic services and relatively higher prices on the price-inelastic
part of their provision. While providing
flexibility, regulation
can be highly controversial. The public will often
perceive such pricing
structures as unfair, even if based on sound economic
principles. Where the
output is more homogeneous, such as gas and electricity,
the regulator may use an
average revenue target, whereby the predicted rise in
A key problem of incentive regulation is
to determine the efficiency factor X. If X
is set too low, the firm
will make excessively large profits and the regulator
will lose face. If it is
set too high, the firm will become unviable. In deciding
on the right value of X,
the regulator may have to be guided by the expert, but
hardly disinterested,
knowledge of the regulated firm. Relations between the regulated and the
regulator may become too close and cordial. Another problem is that the formula
could act as a disincentive to efficiency if more efficient performance were to
lead to subsequent upward revision of X. In practice, rate of return
considerations are implicit in setting X. Even the most expert and experienced
regulator can make mistakes. The UK electricity regulator, for
example, had to undertake a full-scale review less than a year after
establishing new price-caps because the regulated firms’ financial performance
was much better than estimated. Opportunistic behaviour by the regulator can be
highly destabilising.
No comments:
Post a Comment