Monday, November 4, 2013

Information failures


    

    The fourth type of market failure arises because real-world consumers and producers are not perfectly informed about all goods and prices. Where lack of such
knowledge is significant, information failure leads to an inefficient outcome in a
market system. A good example is the health effect of tobacco consumption. In a
free market, no firm has an incentive to circulate information about the hazards
of smoking. The demand curve for cigarettes has shifted outwards above what the
level would be if information was symmetric. It is obvious that tobacco companies
have no incentive to rectify the asymmetry. Nor will any individual have an
incentive to provide such enlightenment. Hence the need for government to step
in. Information failures also provide a rationale for public sector involvement
in activities as diverse as drugs testing, health inspection of restaurants, banking
regulation, insurance and the provision of job search centres for the unemployed.

    These four sources of market failure point to the need for government
intervention. The form of such intervention is the subject of the next section.



Government intervention

    The public sector constitutes the major alternative to free private markets. Hence,
a call for government intervention is generally regarded as the logical consequence
of the diagnosed market failures. As we have seen, public sector activity accounts for sizeable proportions of all countries’ national output. Even in a country as market-oriented as the US, government expenditure accounts for a third of GDP.

    Governments can influence economic activity in three major ways: taxation
and subsidisation, regulation and public provision. Together, they constitute the
main elements in the government’s microeconomic policy.

    In evaluating the different modes of intervention, attention is focused on their
efficiency effects rather than the income distribution effects. Of course, in many
instances the modality of intervention may be determined by equity or, indeed,
purely political considerations. For example, it may be ‘easier’ in political terms
to boost farm incomes by raising food prices than by providing highly transparent
subsidies of an equivalent amount. For that reason, arguments about the
inefficiency of one mode of transfer over another may often fall on deaf ears. Yet
research on more effective ways of intervening, and on the costs and benefits of
different forms of intervention, clearly helps rational decision making.


Taxes and subsidies

    Taxes and subsidies are used extensively to distribute income.
 Subsidies require taxes to finance them, and this raises questions concerning the
optimal structure of taxes. We have already referred to the rules which should
govern indirect taxes: impose high tax rates on activities with low price elasticity
of demand and low broadly-based rates on all other activities, assuming
that the motivation for imposing taxes is simply to obtain revenue for the
government.
   
    While most taxes are imposed for this reason, there is another motivation
which merits discussion. Taxes can sometimes be imposed not primarily in order
to collect revenue, but to direct resources in a particular direction – e.g. a pollution
tax. In other instances, the two motives overlap.By the same token,
while the bulk of subsidies are transfer payments to lower-income groups, many
are provided in order to encourage particular activities and regions

    Returning to the example of the polluting chemicals factory, it is easily shown that, if the government taxes the plant by the amount EF for every unit produced, the firm’s private marginal cost is increased and equals the social marginal cost, leading the firm to produce the socially optimum output level of OQ_2. By taxing the polluter by the value of the damage caused, the government is said to have ‘internalised’ the externality. In general, an optimal government policy taxes firms or individuals for the value of the external cost they cause and subsidises them to the value of the external benefit they create. This is the rationale underlying, for instance, taxes on fuel, and subsidies for education and industrial training.

No comments:

Post a Comment