Thursday, October 31, 2013

Competition policy,privatisation and regulation



    When competition prevails, firms have limited discretion over price. Profit maximization leads them to equate marginal cost to marginal revenue and, because
price is more or less ‘given’ in a competitive market, price equals marginal revenue.
Also, competition forces firms to minimise costs and to search relentlessly for new
and better ways of doing things. Competition encourages innovation. For these
reasons, maintaining a market structure that is open to competition is of the
utmost importance to an efficient economy.

    Our first task in this chapter is to assess the case for competition and to define
the characteristics of a market that encourages competition.

    Our second task is to analyse competition policy. Competition policy refers to
the rules governing the conduct of firms in a market. Without well-developed
and effective competition rules, the market system will not function properly. Yet
a competition regime has to balance the need for active competition on the
domestic market with the equally pressing need to allow firms to attain a
minimum efficient scale and be able to match international competition. On
occasion, it may make sense to tolerate, even encourage, high concentration
ratios in the domestic market. The extension of competition policy to deal with
state aids to industry, and particularly support for state-owned enterprises, is also
examined. We illustrate these issues with examples from the competition policy
of the EU.

    Third, the move to privatisation is analysed. Starting in the 1980s in the UK and
New Zealand, privatisation programmes have been implemented throughout the
world economy. ‘New consensus’ thinking goes far to explaining the rapid spread
of these privatisation programmes. They have been motivated by the desire to
introduce competition where it was absent as well as assisting governments to
improve their financial situation.

    The degree of popular enthusiasm for competition has waxed and waned.
Proponents of competitive market structures are now in the ascendant. In order
to understand why, we must understand the origin of this pro-competitive viewpoint.
It is not necessarily pro-business, though it has coincided with a strongly
pro-business trend in other areas of economic policy. Most businesses feel under
 threat from competition. They are more likely to believe that their problems
derive from excess competition rather than an insufficiency of competition. They
argue for space and time to adjust to the pace of technological advance and to
build up competitive advantage. Getting the balance right between sectoral
strength and optimal competitive pressure is vitally important for economic
performance.

The case for competition

    Competition policy is based on a belief in the economic benefits of competition.
The starting assumption is that market forces are the most effective means of
ensuring efficiency in the allocation of resources, of adapting to change and,
ultimately, of maximising consumer welfare. A much-quoted passage from the
European Commission’s first report on competition policy reflects this basic philosophy:
  
    Competition is the best stimulant of economic activity since it guarantees the widest possible freedom of action to all. An active competition policy ... makes it easier for the demand and supply structures continually to adjust to technological development.Through the interplay of decentralised decision-making machinery, competition enables enterprises continually to improve their efficiency, which is the sine qua non for a steady improvement in living standards and employment prospects within the countries of the Community. From this point of view, competition policy is an essential means for satisfying to a great extent the individual and collective needs of our society.

    Competition has several major advantages over monopoly .First,it provides static benefits through elimination of deadweight losses illustrated in Figure 6.2. This figure shows how competition can lead to more output at a lower price – and it accords with the practical experience of falling prices and higher sales volumes that followed the introduction of competition to formerly monopolized industries ranging from air transport to telecoms. Estimates of the importance of this static effect vary widely, but some have reached as high as 1 per cent of GDP._2 Second, competition brings dynamic benefits:

- It makes organisations internally more efficient by sharpening incentives to
avoid slackness.
-It allows the more efficient organisations to prosper at the expense of the
inefficient .
- It improves dynamic efficiency by stimulating innovation.

The above arguments emphasise efficiency. Equity is another important consideration in competition policy. Governments enforce competition policy in order
to protect weaker companies against the abuse by monopolies of their dominant
market position. Support for the free market presupposes ‘fair’ trading rules and a
level playing field. Defining ‘fairness’ is not, of course, always easy. Moreover,
the dictates of fairness, efficiency and competition sometimes pull in different
directions. Efficiency may require a more concentrated industrial structure than a
government concerned with equity might want to tolerate. Somehow, consistent
rules must be formulated which encourage competition and allow business a
reasonable degree of certainty, but have enough flexibility to deal with cases

where market power may be necessary on technical grounds.

No comments:

Post a Comment