The theory of
monopoly
All firms seek to obtain, consolidate and
expand market power. Many firms have
some degree
of market power but, in the majority of cases, it is not sufficient to
cause
significant deviations from a competitive market outcome. Other firms
occupy
strong monopoly positions. Firms in this category account for a significant,
if not
strictly determinable, proportion of total marketed activity. To understand
the market
system in its entirety, therefore, we need to know how the
system
functions when individual firms possess significant market power.
Specifically,
we need to know the consequences of this power for the firm’s
price and
output decisions, how market power is attained and sustained,
the systemic
implications of market power, and how policy-makers should
respond to
it. We discuss the first two issues in this chapter and the others in
Chapter 7.
The consequences of market power can be
explained with the analysis of the
firm
described in Chapter 5. For simplicity, we take the extreme case of a
singleproduct monopoly. We assume its costs are U-shaped .Demand conditions
are
represented by the demand curve DD, from which the marginal revenue
curve MR can
be derived. Applying the profit-maximisation rule MR # MC gives
the
equilibrium output of OQ_m. The market-clearing price for that output is
OP_m.
The average
cost at that output level is SQ_m. Monopoly profits are then the average
profit margin RS multiplied by output OQ_m. They are represented by the
area of the rectangle P_m_RSF.
Market power means that an individual
firm’s output affects price. Thus,
suppose
production were raised above OQ_m to OQ,. Price would have to fall to
OP,.
Corresponding to that price and output, we have MC # Q,S, and MR # Q,T,.
Note that MR
` MC. This implies that the net increase in revenue obtained by
raising
output by Q_m_Q, is less than the cost of producing that extra
output. Hence
total
profits must be lower at output OQ, than at OQ_m. The profit-maximising
monopolist,
therefore, will cut back sales to OQ_m. The profit-maximising rule
prevents the firm from selling either more or less than OQ_m. This is
why Q_m and P_m are monopoly equilibrium price and quantity.
The economic consequences of the monopoly
are estimated by reference to the
benchmark
case of competition We start off from the monopoly equilibrium. Only this time,
for convenience of exposition, constant costs over the relevant output span are
assumed .The monopoly sells OQ_m at price OP_m. Now assume that
competition is introduced into the industry. Each plant is taken over by an
independent owner. The plants are numerous, so each single owner can have no
influence on price. Hence, MR # P for each individual firm. The
profit-maximising rule leads each firm to produce up to the point where P # MR
# MC. In Figure 6.2, this corresponds to point S, with output OQ_c and
price OP_c .The welfare loss of monopoly is the triangular area RTS.
Intuitively, this represents the total utility derived from the addition of Q_m_Q_c
to extra output, measured by Q_m_RSQ_c less the
actual resource cost of producing it represented by the area under the MC
curve, Q_m_TSQ_c. The creation of this so-called
‘dead-weight’ loss of monopoly constitutes the standard ‘static’ argument
against monopoly.
No comments:
Post a Comment