General principles
Competition law is one of the most
important points of interaction between business,law and economics. Firms need
to understand the rationale and practice of competition legislation and
rules. Competition law is also important because it
impinges so
closely on the welfare of the consumer and the dynamism of the
business
sector. Badly framed competition policy will bring relatively few benefits
to the
consumer at a high cost to business. These costs include not only the costs
of taking or
defending a competition case, but the costs arising when a firm is
uncertain
about the applicability of the law to its behaviour.
While individual countries have their own distinctive
competition regimes,
four general
principles underlie competition policy:
1. Highly concentrated market structures
are more likely to be monopolistic than
less
concentrated structures. Competition policy tends to focus on the former.
2. Competition law is applied to a wide
range of markets, i.e. to public sector
commercial
services and non-profit organisations, as well as to the private
sector.
3. The benefits of competition include
direct benefits to the consumer. But its
indirect
effects on upstream and downstream markets have also to be taken
into account.
An inefficient telecoms industry, for example, affects both the
individual
telephone user and also the pattern of comparative advantage,
through
raising communication costs.
4. Case-by-case studies are necessary to
quantify the net economic benefits and
costs of a
monopoly.
5. Care needs to be taken in devising
remedies which can include sanctions,
declarations,
structural and behavioural actions.
Competition policy – the example of the European Union
The EU’s competition regime provides a
practical illustration of the general
principles of
competition policy.
The principles of the EU’s competition
policy are contained in Articles 85 to 94
of the Treaty
of Rome . Since
the Treaty of Amsterdam came into effect in 1999,
these have
been renumbered Articles 81 to 90. To avoid confusion, we use the
post-1999
numbering in this chapter. These articles cover both uncompetitive
behaviour
between firms and state aids that affect trade between Member States.
The objective
of keeping the EU market open and free from distortion is
addressed by
two key articles, Articles 81 and 82 .
Article 81 prohibits restrictive agreements
relating to price, market shares or production controls, unless specifically
exempted or licensed. Exemptions can be given by the Commission if the
restrictive agreements can be shown to improve efficiency,allow consumers a
‘fair’ share of the resulting benefits, and preserve
some degree of
competition. The exemption clause has been frequently and successfully invoked._8
For example, selective and exclusive dealerships for new car sales are
permitted by virtue of this clause .
Article 82 addresses the problem of abuse
of dominant position. It outlaws unfair
trading
practices, unjustified tie-in clauses and similar arrangements. Concepts
such as
‘dominant position’ and ‘market abuse’ have been subjected to different
interpretations.
Some indication of the complexity of the issues is given in the
summary of the
judgment in the Woodpulp case .
These articles apply in principle to
vertical as well as horizontal agreements
between firms.
Vertical restraints are contracts between firms at different
stages of the
production chain that specify more detailed commitments on the
parties than
simply to exchange a given quantity of goods or services at a given
price per
unit. Examples include selective and exclusive dealerships
discussed in Box 7.4 , retail
price maintenance, service requirements, e.g. undertakings to spend on
advertising and after-sales service, and two-part pricing involving a fixed
charge and a fixed price per unit. VRs essentially involve
agreements
between producers of complementary goods. They are distinguished
from
horizontal restraints .HRs relate to agreements between producers at the
same stage of
the production chain.
Competition law tends to take a permissive
view of VRs. The reason for this is
that abuse of
market power by one producer damages the
producer of the complement .Thus any limit to sales by the manufacturer to
exploit monopoly power reduces sales and profits of the dealer, and vice versa
in case of use of monopoly power by the dealers. Hence both parties are driven
by self-interest to an efficient outcome, very much in the spirit of Adam Smith, and no intervention by the Competition
Authority is needed. In judging VRs, the EU takes a permissive view provided
efficiency is in fact achieved. It adds two other criteria: equity – protection
of small enterprises; and promotion of market integration – hence any measure
preventing ‘parallel’ imports is unfavourably regarded. The more inter-brand
competition in the market, the less the danger of a VR being in breach of
competition law.
No comments:
Post a Comment