The Central Selling Organisation ,based in Switzerland and London , is the
collective
name of companies controlled by De Beers and its associates. It buys
rough diamonds
from the mines, valuing them and selling them to sightholders.
CSO sales
peaked at $6.7 billion in 1997. By keeping rough prices at the highest
sustainable
level, the cartel aims to achieve long-run profit maximisation over
the demand
cycle rather than short-run market clearing at spot prices. The key
characteristics
of the cartel are:
1. The system of producer quotas. Most
significant producers have a long-term and
exclusive
contract to supply a certain proportion of De Beers’ annual diamond
sales.
2. The cartel has created a strong
antidote to any individual producer’s incentive to
cheat. De
Beers backs up the carrot of higher prices with a powerful stick – its
ability to
release from its stocks a supply of any type of diamond. Every
diamond mine
has its own characteristic output. If De Beers chooses to release
more stones of
this characteristic from its stockpile, the stockpile-supported
price can drop
dramatically.
3. De Beers acts as a swing producer. In a
buoyant market, De Beers benefits from
both higher
prices and stock appreciation as goods are sold from the bufferstock.
But in a
depressed market, it absorbs excess supply and reduces its own
production. It
can play this role credibly since its mines are among the cheapest
sources of
fine diamonds in the world and because of the company’s financial
strength. De
Beers holds stocks worth US$4 billion .
4. The cartel pays careful attention to
demand management. It spends over $150
million a year
on advertising. Rather than ride out cyclical fluctuations
the company
wants to drive incremental demand through targeted marketing
Threats to the system
Any interference with the market system
runs the danger of encouraging unintended countervailing and competing
reactions. An official price ceiling gives an
incentive to
sell diamonds outside the system while minimum prices
encourage
over-supply. The diamond cartel is not exempt from these tendencies
and its
operations are under periodic threat.
1. Advertising can influence demand, but
its effects can easily be overwhelmed by
business
cycles and by the ebb and flow of fashion. If De Beers expects a glut of
a certain type
of diamond, it will stop putting it in boxes, but months can pass
before the
effect of the move is felt in the market for polished stones.
2. De Beers’ sway over customers for rough
diamonds is not matched by its influence on customers for polished diamonds –
jewellers and their suppliers. This
makes it
difficult for De Beers to control prices to the end-buyer.
3. New entrants add uncertainty to the
diamond market. The new Ekati diamond
mine in Canada accounts
for 6 per cent of world supply. Political instability in
Africa and Russia can also
create problems by magnifying the incentive to
cheat and
favouring short-term over long-term perspectives of national interest.
This explains
why De Beers has embarked on a marketing campaign to
create a De
Beers brand rather than to promote diamonds in general.
4. De Beers’ main concern is the
confidence of its members. If they sense that the
cartel lacks
the strength needed to fulfil its role as swing producer, cartel
members will
be tempted to sell their diamonds before others do the same. The
main cement to
this cartel, as to others, is the conviction that centralised
selling and buffer-stock
management are in its collective interest.
No comments:
Post a Comment