Monday, October 28, 2013

Access and quality of service


Each of the above techniques refers to ways by which the regulator can prevent
abuse of monopoly power in the form of excessive charges to the consumer and
excessive profits. But monopoly power can also be curbed by determining the conditions of access to the service or sector. For example, in the case of network operators in electricity, gas, telecoms or air transport, the monopolist has an obvious
incentive to provide access to its network on unfavourable terms. To counteract
this, the regulator must devise and open a fair and transparent licensing scheme
for new entrants. Considerable research has gone into establishing how access
charges for connection to networks should be determined. The efficient component
pricing rule has been developed to deal with such situations. It provides that
new entrants must pay an amount to cover the marginal cost of access to the
network plus some contribution towards fixed costs of setting it up which were
borne by the original state firm. This rule has many flaws, and there is no simple
rule of thumb for determining the relevant fixed and marginal costs. Another
factor here is that some providers may have universal service obligations, i.e. an
obligation to provide a minimum set of services of specified quality to all users at
an affordable price. The regulator must also have regard to the quality of service
offered by existing and new operators to the consumer and by the network owner
to competing operators. The existing operator must not be allowed to favour its
own downstream  arm over competitors. Finally, there is usually provision
for complaints procedures and for the development of customer charters.
    The above considerations demonstrate that regulation may be necessary, and
better than no regulation, but it is by no means costless. Regulators do not come
cheaply. They need large staffs of economists and lawyers. Regulators can be of
variable quality and regulatory capture is an ever-present danger. Their decisions
can always be subject to long and expensive appeal, just as in the case of competition law. Regulation cannot be considered a satisfactory substitute for
competition. The high cost of imposing regulation underlines the importance
of competition as an alternative, more efficient, policing device for curbing
excessive profits. In short, the best regulator will often be one that succeeds in
making itself redundant. Over time, emphasis must be placed on deregulation
and exposure to international competition as the most efficient way forward.
    When thinking of competition most businesses see their problem as one of excess
competition, not a lack of it. This is understandable from the perspective of an
individual firm already established in an industry. Competitive pressure has
increased in most economies. But the notion of competition being ‘excessive’ sits
uneasily with economic thinking on the role of free markets. Competition affords
opportunities for new firms to enter the industry. From these firms’ perspective,
the problem may appear one of too little, not too much competition.
Competitive pressure, however, gives firms an incentive to search more vigorously
for ways of protecting their domestic market, by developing market niches
and, if necessary, by circumventing competition legislation. As a result, new
entrants to an industry can be deterred by unfair trade practices, and financially
weaker firms can be discriminated against in the process, unless protected by law. The consumer, too, can suffer discrimination as larger firmsbuild up their war chests and tighten their hold on their market share. In short,competition policy is still needed.Competition policy should aim to be transparent, easy to implement and predictable. The need for case-by-case assessment, taking account of each market’s special features, can result in complex legal cases and much uncertainty.

    Competition policy is not a flawless set of precepts which can impose competition
in a costless way. It can be expensive and inefficient to enforce and can
be subverted and distorted. Yet, for all that, the secretary general of Unice,
the federation of European industry, reflected the weight of business opinion in
his assertion that the essential corollary of competitiveness [is] strong competition
policy.

    State-owned enterprises in formerly nontraded sectors of the economy – telecoms,transport, energy and public utilities – have become a focus for competition
policy in recent years. These enterprises were once regarded as ‘natural’
monopolies, but thinking has changed. Governments have become convinced
of the efficiency gains that can be obtained through a more market-oriented
framework. The European Commission has been particularly active in promoting
competition in these sectors through the use of competition law.

    Competition policy has been further bolstered by setting limits on the amount
of state aid provided by EU Member States to various industrial and regional initiatives.This type of action is welcomed by the weaker Member States because
they are unable to afford the cost of matching the subsidies offered by richer
Member States. The EU’s strategic policy to favour competition is also evident in
its support for SMEs.

    A degree of tension between competition and industrial policy is to be
expected. Prior to the Second World War, cartelisation was seen as a way of building up more efficient and technically progressive industries in Germany and
Switzerland. Japan also had a tradition of looking with suspicion on ‘excessive’
competition because of its possible detrimental effects on an industry’s capacity
to exploit fully the economies of scale. According to one authority, the Japanese
authorities feared ‘excessive’ competition as much as monopoly as a potential
source of inefficiency._14 Their predilection for limiting competition and encouraging
mergers, vertical and horizontal firm groupings, and inter-firm operating
agreements, has been fundamentally at odds with anti-trust policy. In the case of
the automobile industry, for example, the Ministry for International Trade and
Industry sought to limit production to one firm and, failing that, a target
of ‘at most’ three firms was set. It proved impossible to restrict competition in this
way, however. The vigorous competition between domestic firms that prevailed
in postwar Japan proved to be an important source of vitality for the Japanese
economy. Yet, to this day, some countries maintain a more tolerant approach to
cartels than would be countenanced by most European countries. Keeping the
domestic market contestable often entails an element of compromise between
the objective of avoiding market dominance and allowing a technically efficient
size of firm.


No comments:

Post a Comment