Thursday, October 3, 2013

The market system in action


The market system in action
The free market comprises a series of interconnected markets. These markets are
assumed to be highly competitive and to operate free of government interference.
This is an initial simplifying assumption, which will be relaxed in later chapters.
In reality, many markets are subject to monopolistic influences, and government
intervention in the market system is a feature of even the most enthusiastically
capitalist society. Indeed, in some circumstances, such intervention can be shown
to be a necessary condition for achieving economic efficiency. Additionally, we
assume a stable institutional framework of law and order within which market
transactions can be conducted in an orderly and predictable way.

Given these conditions, the market system allocates resources between different
uses and among different people. It acts as an equilibrating mechanism between
supply and demand. Prices act as signals; and the price system is the coordinating
mechanism which ensures that markets ‘clear’, i.e. that supply equals demand in
each market.

The operation of the price system is by no means obvious. The fact that a free
market system works at all may be considered, if one stops to think about it, as
somewhat miraculous. Millions of individual decisions are taken daily in a market
economy by producers and consumers. These decisions are independent and
uncoordinated. Yet, by and large, goods and services are available in the shops to
meet consumer demands as they arise. The market system is the mechanism
which brings this about in an automatic and efficient manner.

The market system

The market system can be sketched by reference to three major markets – the
product market, the labour market and the capital market – and two primary sets
of participants: firms and households  The product market comprises
the markets for individual goods and services; the labour market involves
the buying and selling of labour; and the capital market deals with the lending and
borrowing of capital. Each market involves the participation of firms and households.
Thus, households sell their labour to firms; and, with the salaries so earned,they buy goods and services from firms. Firms produce goods and services byhiring labour and capital from households .Households andfirms also interact on the capital market. If individuals choose not to spend alltheir income, their savings are channelled to firms by intermediaries such asbanks and pension funds. If they choose to spend more than their income, loanswill be supplied by the same intermediaries. The lines in Figure 3.1 run bothways. However, the savings arrow from households to firms is thicker thanthe reverse arrow from firms to households in recognition of the fact that thecorporate sector is the key investor and borrower in an economy. Households aregenerally net suppliers of funds to firms.

This is a much simplified conceptualisation of the market system as we know itin the real world, but it is sufficient to illustrate the strong interconnectionsbetween markets. Households need to sell their labour to firms in order to be ableto buy goods. Unless households spend their incomes on purchases of goods andservices, there will not be any demand for their labour. Or, to take another example, if firms do not invest, there will be no demand for household savings: savings are useful only in so far as there is an investor somewhere ready and willing to use them for investment. Clearly, a mechanism must exist to bring these disparate and independent decisions into equilibrium. A sustained disequilibriumin one part of this closely interconnected market system can have serious repercussions on other parts of the system. The market system is, in other words, a general equilibrium system. If anything goes wrong with the market mechanism, an economy could run into serious trouble.

Two other market participants must be considered – the foreign sector and the
government sector. Firms do not have to sell their entire output to domestic consumers.They also have the option of exporting. Likewise, households can
import goods and services instead of buying the output of domestic firms.
Imports, exports and the foreign trade market are an integral part of an analysis
of the market system. Factors of production such as capital and labour can also
be traded internationally. The rise in global capital mobility, especially between
developed countries, has meant that the domestic economy is no longer
restricted to domestic savings for its supply of investment funds. The foreign
sector has been growing rapidly in relative importance during the postwar
period.

The government is also an important participant in the market. Government
spending amounts to about 40 per cent of total national expenditure in industrial
countries generally and exceeds 50 per cent in a number of European countries.
Sweden’s ratio is 50 per cent Even in an economy as free market-oriented as the US, the government’s share of total spending ratio is 30 per cent .The spending ratio, however, gives only a rough impression of the extent of government influence in the market system. Public intervention takes many forms in addition to government spending. Official regulations impinge on all areas of economic life – planning requirements for new buildings, health and safety regulations and environmental restrictions, for example. State-owned commercial companies are another vehicle of government influence not reflected in the spending:GDP ratio.



No comments:

Post a Comment